顯示具有 corporate governance 標籤的文章。 顯示所有文章
顯示具有 corporate governance 標籤的文章。 顯示所有文章

2025年7月16日 星期三

Is Company Law a Game Without Skin? Why Modern Corporate Structures Contradict Taleb's Core Principles

 

Is Company Law a Game Without Skin? Why Modern Corporate Structures Contradict Taleb's Core Principles


Nassim Nicholas Taleb, the provocative author and statistician, famously champions the concept of "skin in the game" – the idea that those who make decisions should bear the consequences of those decisions, good or bad. It's about symmetry in incentives and disincentives, asserting that a lack of "skin in the game" fosters moral hazard, encourages reckless risk-taking, and ultimately hinders systems from learning and evolving. When we hold modern company law up to this exacting standard, several core tenets appear to fundamentally contradict Taleb's principles, creating a corporate landscape where some can reap rewards without fully facing the repercussions.

The Shield of Limited Liability: A One-Way Bet?

At the heart of modern company law lies limited liability, a foundational principle that shields shareholders from corporate debts beyond their initial investment. While crucial for capital formation and risk diversification, this very mechanism stands as a stark contradiction to "skin in the game."

Consider the asymmetry: shareholders stand to gain immensely if a company thrives – their shares multiply in value, often without limit. Yet, if the company falters, their personal assets remain protected. Their downside is capped at their initial investment, while their upside is virtually limitless. This structure, Taleb would argue, encourages excessive risk-taking. Why? Because the potential gains are uncapped, but the painful losses are contained, externalized to creditors, employees, or even the broader public. It's a classic case of moral hazard, where the decision-makers (or those whose interests are prioritized by management) aren't fully exposed to the negative outcomes of their choices.

The Agency Problem: Owners, Managers, and Misaligned Interests

In large public corporations, there's a pronounced separation of ownership and control. Shareholders, the ultimate owners, are often a dispersed group with little direct influence over daily operations or strategic decisions. Instead, these responsibilities fall to directors and executives.

While executives' compensation often includes performance-linked bonuses and stock options, this doesn't always equate to genuine "skin in the game" in Taleb's sense. Their personal wealth might be tied to short-term stock fluctuations rather than the long-term health and survival of the enterprise. They rarely face the same existential risk as an entrepreneur whose entire livelihood hinges on their venture. Taleb is deeply critical of bureaucracies where decision-makers are insulated from the fallout of their actions. In a large corporate structure, responsibility can become so diffused that true individual accountability for negative outcomes is rare, a stark contrast to the direct feedback loop "skin in the game" demands.

Fiduciary Duties: A Partial Solution?

Company law imposes fiduciary duties on directors and officers, compelling them to act in the best interests of the company and its shareholders. This is often presented as a mechanism to align interests and ensure responsible governance.

However, the practical application of these duties can fall short. Enforcing them is often difficult, and their interpretation can sometimes prioritize short-term shareholder value over long-term sustainability or broader societal impact. Furthermore, the legal and practical avenues for shareholders to hold directors personally accountable for poor decisions are cumbersome. It's exceedingly rare for directors to suffer personal financial ruin for corporate failures (unless there's clear evidence of fraud or gross negligence), which again diverges from Taleb's notion of a "filter" that weeds out those prone to bad judgment by making them directly bear the financial consequences.

The "Professional" Manager: A Lack of Personal Stake

Taleb frequently draws a distinction between the owner-operator, who has their personal capital and reputation on the line, and the "professional" manager, who manages other people's money. Company law, by facilitating the growth of large corporations reliant on hired management, inherently promotes this "professional" model. In this setup, decision-makers may lack the profound personal financial or reputational exposure that characterizes someone running their own business, diminishing their "skin in the game."


In essence, while company law has undeniably spurred economic growth by facilitating capital formation and risk diversification, it simultaneously engenders systemic incentives that appear to be at odds with Nassim Nicholas Taleb's principles. By insulating decision-makers and investors from the full spectrum of consequences, modern corporate structures raise fundamental questions about true accountability, efficient risk management, and the very nature of robust, antifragile systems.


2025年6月17日 星期二

Whose Skin Is It Anyway? Big Pharma's Shell Game



Whose Skin Is It Anyway? Big Pharma's Shell Game

 You ever wonder about some things? I mean, really wonder. Like how a pharmaceutical company can push a drug, off-label, telling its sales reps to do something illegal, and then when it all blows up, the company pays a multi-billion dollar fine, and the folks who were really calling the shots just... walk away? Or move to another company, still pulling down the big bucks. It just doesn't sit right.

I was listening to Lisa Pratta the other day  ( https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=27qUyMuYZJw ), a pharmaceutical sales rep for 32 years, and she saw it all. Five-day snorkeling trips to Bimini for doctors. A $15,000 Birkin handbag. An Armani suit because a rep didn't like a doctor's old one. Concert box seats, Eagles games, Phillies games, even strip clubs and lap dances. You give a guy a Birkin bag, do you really think he's going to be objective about prescribing your medication? Common sense tells you no.

Then there's the Acthar story. FDA says one thing, five vials for 20 days. Company, Questcor, says "Nah, sell it as one vial for five days." Why? To get Medicare and Medicaid approval. And the poor patients? They don't get better. They get worse. Lisa saw a woman, Melanie, in her early 30s, already with a cane, asking for her opinion on the drug. And Lisa, knowing it was illegal to give medical advice, had to give the company line, then went to the bathroom and cried. She knew Melanie wasn't going to get better. She knew the company was selling snake oil, essentially, for a huge profit.

And the sales managers? They'd yell at reps for not pushing the illegal dosage. "You're going to do this! I don't care!" Veins bulging out of their necks. My goodness. If you yell at someone to break the law, and that law-breaking puts patients at risk, shouldn't your neck be on the line?

They'd even run these "studies" with doctors. Pay them $500 per patient for ten patients. Call it research. Lisa called it a "bogus study." It wasn't for science. It was to "subliminally condition" doctors to be "Acthar cheerleaders." To change their prescribing habits. Because the competitor, Solu-Medrol, wasn't "giving me any cash."

This is where you need a healthy dose of "skin in the game." It's not complicated, really. Nassim Taleb talks about it. It’s about symmetry. If you stand to gain from something, you should also stand to lose if it goes wrong. Right now, in big pharma, the upside is for the executives, and the downside is for the company (a fine, which is just a cost of doing business), and worst of all, for the patients.

So, how do you fix it? You put some real skin in the game.

First, law design. When a pharmaceutical company is hit with a multi-billion dollar fine for illegal practices – something like off-label promotion that puts patients at risk – that fine shouldn't just be absorbed by the shareholders or the company's balance sheet. A significant portion of it, say, 20% or 30%, should be personally recouped from the bonuses and stock options of the executives, board members, and sales leadership who were in charge during the period of the malpractice. And if they've moved on to other companies? Doesn't matter. Claw it back. Make it retroactive. Make it painful. That's real skin.

Second, company finance and bonuses. Stop tying executive bonuses solely to sales figures, especially when those sales figures might be inflated by illegal or unethical means. Tie them to patient outcomes. Tie them to FDA compliance rates. If your drug is found to be used off-label, or causing harm because of unapproved dosages, those bonuses should evaporate faster than a politician's promise. And hold those bonuses in escrow for five to ten years. If malpractice comes to light within that period, the money goes straight to victim compensation or public health funds, not into some CEO's offshore account.

Third, accountability for managers. If a sales manager is caught pressuring reps to break the law, they shouldn't just get a performance review. They should face personal legal consequences, including jail time if the actions led to patient harm. You put a manager in jail for encouraging illegal behavior, and suddenly, those bulging veins might calm down a bit.

We're not suckers. We're getting sick at the expense of someone laughing all the way to the bank. It infuriates me, and it should infuriate every American. Demand that the people who benefit from risk also bear the cost of failure. It's the only way to demand change.